Publications-NSC Projects

Article View/Open

Publication Export

Google ScholarTM

NCCU Library

Citation Infomation

Related Publications in TAIR

題名 台灣股票市場的權益溢酬(1/2)
作者 周行一
日期 2003
上傳時間 18-Apr-2007 16:41:48 (UTC+8)
Publisher 臺北市:國立政治大學財務管理學系
摘要 With the assumption that the expected-utility maximizing investors with standard additively separable state preferences and constant relative risk aversion (CRRA), standard financial economic theory predicts the level of risk premium a risky asset would offer. Locus (1978) and Breeden (1979) examine equilibrium stochastic pattern of a risky asset`s return in a pure single-good exchange economy. With homogeneous belief and CRRA, each individual maximizes his intertemporal expected utility of consumption by acquiring the claim of a risky asset that implies the risk level he can afford. In the famous consumption-based CAPM model (CCAPM model), the covariance of the return on the risky asset with the per capita consumption measures the risk of this risky asset. Using the covariance, one can get a theoretically expected risk premium based on the relation similar to that of CAPM. Based on a standard equilibrium model, with individuals maximizing an additively separable CRRA utility function, Mehra and Prescott (1985) calculate the coefficient of relative risk aversion needed to justify the US historical equity risk premium and conclude that it is too high to be reasonable. It took Mehra and Prescott almost six years to convince a skeptical profession for their paper (1985) to be published and attended by financial economists. Table 1 shows the estimates of Mehra (2002) on the long-term real rate of return of the US stock market, yields of a relatively riskless asset, and the risk premium derived from the two estimates. From 1889-1978, a period that does not include the recent bull period, the annual real rate of return on equities was about 7%. For the 1889-2000 period, the annual rate of return was 7.9 %. The standard deviation of annual rate of return was about 20%. In addition, as Table 2 shows, other countries have similar returns. The US T-bills have returned about 1% with a 4% standard deviation.
描述 核定金額:615900元
資料類型 report
dc.coverage.temporal 計畫年度:92 起迄日期:20030801~20040731en_US
dc.creator (作者) 周行一zh_TW
dc.date (日期) 2003en_US
dc.date.accessioned 18-Apr-2007 16:41:48 (UTC+8)en_US
dc.date.accessioned 8-Sep-2008 16:34:23 (UTC+8)-
dc.date.available 18-Apr-2007 16:41:48 (UTC+8)en_US
dc.date.available 8-Sep-2008 16:34:23 (UTC+8)-
dc.date.issued (上傳時間) 18-Apr-2007 16:41:48 (UTC+8)en_US
dc.identifier (Other Identifiers) 922416H004028.pdfen_US
dc.identifier.uri (URI) http://tair.lib.ntu.edu.tw:8000/123456789/4136en_US
dc.identifier.uri (URI) https://nccur.lib.nccu.edu.tw/handle/140.119/4136-
dc.description (描述) 核定金額:615900元en_US
dc.description.abstract (摘要) With the assumption that the expected-utility maximizing investors with standard additively separable state preferences and constant relative risk aversion (CRRA), standard financial economic theory predicts the level of risk premium a risky asset would offer. Locus (1978) and Breeden (1979) examine equilibrium stochastic pattern of a risky asset`s return in a pure single-good exchange economy. With homogeneous belief and CRRA, each individual maximizes his intertemporal expected utility of consumption by acquiring the claim of a risky asset that implies the risk level he can afford. In the famous consumption-based CAPM model (CCAPM model), the covariance of the return on the risky asset with the per capita consumption measures the risk of this risky asset. Using the covariance, one can get a theoretically expected risk premium based on the relation similar to that of CAPM. Based on a standard equilibrium model, with individuals maximizing an additively separable CRRA utility function, Mehra and Prescott (1985) calculate the coefficient of relative risk aversion needed to justify the US historical equity risk premium and conclude that it is too high to be reasonable. It took Mehra and Prescott almost six years to convince a skeptical profession for their paper (1985) to be published and attended by financial economists. Table 1 shows the estimates of Mehra (2002) on the long-term real rate of return of the US stock market, yields of a relatively riskless asset, and the risk premium derived from the two estimates. From 1889-1978, a period that does not include the recent bull period, the annual real rate of return on equities was about 7%. For the 1889-2000 period, the annual rate of return was 7.9 %. The standard deviation of annual rate of return was about 20%. In addition, as Table 2 shows, other countries have similar returns. The US T-bills have returned about 1% with a 4% standard deviation.-
dc.format applicaiton/pdfen_US
dc.format.extent bytesen_US
dc.format.extent 117778 bytesen_US
dc.format.extent 117778 bytes-
dc.format.extent 17326 bytes-
dc.format.mimetype application/pdfen_US
dc.format.mimetype application/pdfen_US
dc.format.mimetype application/pdf-
dc.format.mimetype text/plain-
dc.language zh-TWen_US
dc.language.iso zh-TWen_US
dc.publisher (Publisher) 臺北市:國立政治大學財務管理學系en_US
dc.rights (Rights) 行政院國家科學委員會en_US
dc.title (題名) 台灣股票市場的權益溢酬(1/2)zh_TW
dc.type (資料類型) reporten